By Robert
J. Samuelson
WASHINGTON,
DC: What we are witnessing in Europe—and what may loom for the
United States—is the exhaustion of the modern social order. Since
the early 1800s, industrial societies rested on a marriage of
economic growth and political stability. Economic progress improved
people’s lives and anchored their loyalty to the state. Wars,
depressions, revolutions and class conflicts interrupted the cycle.
But over time, prosperity fostered stable democracies in the United
States, Europe and parts of Asia. The present economic crisis might
reverse this virtuous process. Slower economic expansion would feed
political instability, and vice versa. This would be a historic and
ominous break from the past.
It’s this specter that hovers
over the US election and the entire developed world, though it need
not come true. Modern economies — especially the American —
possess great recuperative powers.
Democratic traditions
are strong. Still, a reversal can’t be excluded, because most
advanced countries face slower economic growth, even if (hardly
certain) they successfully navigate the fallout of the global
financial crisis. Semi-stagnant societies can’t meet all
expectations for jobs, higher wages and government benefits.
Political institutions then lose legitimacy. Europe could foretell
this dismal spiral.
Demographics alone suggest slower economic
growth. The aging of the United States, Japan and most European
countries reduces the labor force growth, because there are fewer new
workers compared to retiring workers. In the United States, average
labor force growth is now reckoned by the Congressional Budget Office
at 0.5 percent a year, a third of its post-1950 average. Elsewhere,
prospects are worse. In Germany, the labor force is barely growing;
in Japan, it’s declining. In the short run, a slowing labor force
cushions unemployment. In the long run, it reduces economic
growth.
From 1950 to 2011, US economic growth averaged
3.3 percent annually, divided roughly equally between average labor
force increases of 1.5 percent annually and productivity gains of 1.8
percent. (Productivity — efficiency — generally reflects new
technologies, better management and more skilled workers.) With the
labor force increasing more slowly, the pace of potential U.S.
economic expansion would drop to 2.3 percent annually, assuming that
productivity gains stay the same. Unfortunately, that’s an iffy
assumption.
In a fascinating paper, economist Robert Gordon of
Northwestern University speculates that productivity increases have
peaked. Per capita income gains may gradually slow to half or less of
their historical rate. Most economists, he writes, believe “economic
growth is a continuous process that will persist forever.” It may
not, he argues.
Gordon identifies three industrial
“revolutions.” The first began in England around 1750 and
featured cotton spinning, the steam engine and railroads. The second,
dating from 1870 to 1900, was the most significant and involved the
harnessing of electricity, the invention of the internal combustion
engine and the advent of indoor plumbing with running water. These,
he contends, triggered other advances: appliances, highways, suburbs,
airplanes, elevators and modern communications (telephones,
televisions).
Gordon is less impressed with the third
revolution: computers, starting around 1960 when big companies first
used “mainframes.” True, they automated airline reservations,
banking transactions and clerical work. Secretaries “began to
disappear.” More recently, e-commerce has exploded. But Gordon sees
the Internet, smartphones and tablets as tilted toward entertainment,
not labor-saving.
High productivity gains from cyber
technologies “had faded away by 2004,” he argues.
Technological
innovation, though faltering, will continue, Gordon writes. Think
more driverless cars and new cancer drugs. But he argues that the
effects on average American living standards will be muted.
Less-skilled workers from lackluster schools will cut productivity
and wage growth further.
Greater
inequality will steer some gains to the wealthy. Higher taxes to
cover budget deficits and transfers to the elderly will squeeze
take-home pay. Health insurance costs (which he does not mention)
would do the same. Though not preordained, Gordon’s prophecies
suggest a long era of stunted economic growth.
Economic
progress — progress that people can feel and that feeds hope and
optimism — favors political stability. If progress shrinks or
vanishes, stability may suffer. People lose faith and feel betrayed.
The role of economic growth in advanced societies is increasingly to
satisfy the many claims from different groups. People can (or think
they can) pursue their self-interest without harming the common good.
When the system reduces or rejects many of those claims, as is now
happening in Europe, the pursuit of self-interest becomes more
contentious and destructive.
What’s
happening in America is different in degree, but not in kind, from
what’s occurring in Europe.
Stalled
economic growth there is straining the political system’s ability
to meet all expectations.
People
take to the streets; extremist parties expand. To avoid Europe’s
fate, we should reduce people’s claims on the system and strive for
faster economic growth. That’s the lesson. If we ignore it, history
may slip into reverse.
©
2012, The Washington Post Writers Group
No comments:
Post a Comment